SYLLABUS
(This syllabus is not part of the opinion of the Court. It has been prepared by the Office of the Clerk for the convenience of the
reader. It has been neither reviewed nor approved by the Supreme Court. Please note that, in the interests of brevity, portions
of any opinion may not have been summarized).
Susan Kaufman v. i-Stat Corporation, et als. (A-49-99)
Argued May 1, 2000 -- Decided July 27, 2000
LaVECCHIA, J., writing for a majority of the Court.
The issue in this appeal is whether a class of plaintiffs in a common-law action for fraud can prove the element of
reliance through the presumption of fraud on the market, a theory adopted by the U.S. Supreme Court in Basic, Inc. v.
Levinson,
485 U.S. 224 (1988), which allows plaintiffs to bring class actions under federal securities fraud law by excusing
them from the burden of proving individual reliance on a misrepresentation. Instead, under the fraud-on-the-market theory,
plaintiffs may establish the reliance element of their claims by showing that they purchased securities in the secondary markets
at attractive prices that had been artificially affected by an issuer's misrepresentations and omissions.
i-Stat is a public New Jersey corporation that manufactures and markets diagnostic blood-analysis equipment
designed to assist medical professionals at the point of patient care. The corporation's stock is traded on the NASDAQ
National Market System. On May 9, 1995, i-Stat announced its financial results for the first fiscal quarter of 1995. The
company reported net sales of $3,359,000 - about $1.7 million more than sales reported for the same period in the previous
year.
On May 22, 1995, Kaufman purchased one hundred shares of i-Stat common stock at 21 3/4, a total investment of
$2175. The stock climbed to 43 3/4 by September of that year. However, in January 1996, The New York Times reported that
the largest institutional holder of i-Stat had made charitable contributions to hospitals to enable them to obtain i-Stat's
diagnostic equipment. In addition, in March 1996, The Wall Street Journal reported that the Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC) was investigating i-Stat's business. The article revealed that some of i-Stat's sales had been loans of
the products to hospitals on a trial basis rather than actual sales. i-Stat responded with a press release that confirmed the SEC's
investigation and inquiry into its sales procedures. On that same day, i-Stat's shares, which had been declining, tumbled 2 ½ to
28 3/4. Nearly one-sixth of the outstanding i-Stat shares traded on that date.
On May 20, 1996, Kaufman sold 50 shares of the i-Stat stock at 20 1/4. On June 19, 1996, she filed suit as putative
class representative on behalf of all purchasers of i-Stat common stock between May 9, 1995 and March 19, 1996. She alleged
common-law fraud and negligent misrepresentation, contending that i-Stat's deliberately false and misleading statement
regarding its financial status and deceptive sales practices inflated the stock price during the class period. i-Stat filed an
answer alleging various affirmative defenses. The parties stipulated that Kaufman did not actually or directly receive or rely
on any communication containing any misrepresentation, or on any communication that omitted material facts; that she
purchased her stock through a brokerage firm and did not directly receive or rely on any communication from that firm
concerning the i-Stat purchase; and that she relied exclusively on the integrity of the market price of i-Stat stock at the time of
the purchase.
i-Stat subsequently moved for summary judgment on the ground that Kaufman failed to state a cause of action in
fraud or in negligent misrepresentation because she could not satisfy the actual reliance requirement in each. The trial court
granted i-Stat's motion, dismissing Kaufman's claims. The trial court rejected the fraud-on-the-market theory as a substitute
for reliance. Under that theory, the market price reflects the value of the stock to the investor based on all of the information
available at the time. Therefore, an investor relying on a price that is actually based on misrepresentations is entitled to
recover damages when he or she trades at a loss.
On appeal, the Appellate Division reversed the dismissal of Kaufman's complaint on the common-law fraud claim but
affirmed the dismissal of the negligent misrepresentation claim. Noting that New Jersey already allows proof of indirect
reliance to satisfy the reliance element of a common-law fraud claim, the court concluded that Kaufman's reliance on the
integrity of the market price of the security was sufficient to satisfy the reliance requirement of a common-law fraud claim
when the security was inflated artificially by the corporation's deliberate false statements. The court concluded that the
reasoning of the federal securities law cases, which allows the reliance element of a securities fraud claim under section 10(b)
of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 to be satisfied by reliance on the market price of the security, should apply to common
law fraud claims for securities fraud because the reliance element of a securities fraud claim under these regulatory provisions
is substantially the same as in a common law fraud action.
The court declined to extend this form of proof of reliance to a negligent misrepresentation claim, citing public policy
considerations in favor of a more limited scope of liability for negligent communication of fraudulent misrepresentations.
The Supreme Court granted Kaufman's petition for certification.
HELD: In a common-law action for fraud, a plaintiff may not establish the element of reliance on a misrepresentation or
omission through the presumption of fraud on the market.
1. Because Congress' passage of the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of 1995 (and other subsequent federal
legislation) has made litigating class-action strike suits by investors when the price of a stock has declined much more difficult,
many plaintiffs have increasingly turned to state courts. (pp. 11-16)
2. The federal courts with jurisdiction in New Jersey have rejected the idea that fraud on the market can create a common-law
action for fraud. (pp. 16-17)
3. Although federalism permits the state and national governments to resolve similar matters in different ways, a court's
decision to follow its own lead ought to be firmly grounded in public policy. Thus, the question in this matter is whether the
public interest in the development of the common law of fraud is served by Kaufman's contention that the fraud-on-the-market
theory should be permitted to be used in New Jersey, despite a contrary conclusion in the many other jurisdictions that have
considered the same question. (pp. 17-19)
4. The element of reliance is the same for fraud and negligent misrepresentation. The actual receipt and consideration of any
misstatement remains central to the case of any plaintiff seeking to prove that he or she was deceived by the misstatement or
omission. (pp. 19-22)
5. The doctrine of indirect reliance requires a plaintiff to have relied on the substance of the allegedly fraudulent claim,
regardless of whether the claim was received directly from the issuer or some third party. If proven, indirect reliance is an
element of a claim of fraud. (pp. 22-24)
6. Kaufman, by her admissions, has failed to establish that she relied, however indirectly, on the misstatements of i-Stat and its
management, and thus, under the traditional standard for proof of reliance, has failed to make out a claim for fraud. (p. 24)
7. Since the U.S. Supreme Court's acceptance of fraud on the market twelve years ago in Basic, no state court with the
authority to consider whether Basic is persuasive has chosen to apply it to claims arising under its own state's law, and an
examination of its intellectual underpinning does not support an expansion of the common law. (pp. 27-34)
8. Accepting fraud on the market as proof of reliance in a New Jersey common law fraud action would undercut the public
interest in preventing forum shopping, weaken New Jersey's law of indirect reliance, and run contrary to the policy direction
of the Legislature and Congress. (pp. 34-35)
JUSTICE STEIN has filed a separate dissenting opinion in which JUSTICES O'HERN and LONG join. Justice
Stein believes that the Appellate Division's thorough and well-reasoned opinion reflects the correct disposition of the issue.
He notes that under the indirect reliance principle accepted by New Jersey courts to establish reliance in a common-law fraud
action, i-Stat's intentional fraud may be actionable as a common law fraud even though the authors of the false information did
not communicate it directly to the plaintiff. Justice Stein views the question as one of whether the principle of indirect reliance
applies in the context of purchasers of publicly traded securities where the fraud was perpetrated generally on the public with
the intention that all purchasers of the securities would be defrauded. Finally, Justice Stein notes that the fraud-on-the-market
theory is merely a rebuttable presumption of reliance and that, as such, defendants may rebut proof of the elements giving rise
to the presumption, or show that the misrepresentation in fact did not lead to a distortion of price, or that an individual plaintiff
traded or would have traded despite his or her knowing the statement was false.
Judgment of the Appellate Division allowing the reliance element of a fraud claim to be proven by the fraud-on-the
market theory is REVERSED, and the judgment of the Superior Court, Law Division, is REINSTATED, dismissing
plaintiff's action.
CHIEF JUSTICE PORITZ and JUSTICES COLEMAN and VERNIERO join in JUSTICE LaVECCHIA's opinion.
JUSTICE STEIN filed a separate dissenting opinion in which JUSTICES O'HERN and LONG join.
SUPREME COURT OF NEW JERSEY
A-
49 September Term 1999
SUSAN KAUFMAN, on behalf of
herself and all others
similarly situated,
Plaintiff-Respondent,
v.
i-STAT CORPORATION; WILLIAM
P. MOFFITT; LIONEL N.
STERLING; IMANTS R. LAUKS and
MATTHIAS PLUM, JR.,
Defendants-Appellants.
______________________________
Argued May 1, 2000 -- Decided July 27, 2000
On certification to the Superior Court, Appellate
Division, whose opinion is reported at
324 N.J.
Super. 344 (1999).
Lawrence M. Rolnick argued the cause for appellants
(Lowenstein Sandler, attorneys; Mr. Rolnick and
Edward T. Dartley, on the brief).
William C. Fredericks, a member of the New York
Bar, argued the cause for respondent (Miles M.
Tepper, attorney).
The opinion of the Court was delivered by
LaVECCHIA, J.
This appeal presents the question whether a class of plaintiffs in
a common-law action for fraud can prove the element of reliance through
the presumption of a fraud on the market. The theory of fraud on the
market, as described by the United States Supreme Court in Basic Inc.
v. Levinson,
485 U.S. 224,
108 S. Ct. 978,
99 L. Ed.2d 194 (1988),
allows plaintiffs to bring class actions under federal securities-fraud
law by excusing those plaintiffs from the burden of proving individual
reliance. Instead, plaintiffs may establish the reliance element of
their claims by showing that they purchased securities in the secondary
markets at attractive prices that had been artificially affected by an
issuer's misrepresentations and omissions.
Plaintiff Susan Kaufman held shares of defendant i-Stat
Corporation (i-Stat) over a period during which i-Stat allegedly
misrepresented certain financial matters and the misrepresentations
were discovered and publicized. The misrepresentations were never made
to Kaufman by i-Stat or any intermediary. Kaufman relied on the price
of the stock in her decisions, and now contends that, because i-Stat's
misrepresentations were reflected in the share price, she can make out
claims for common-law fraud and negligent misrepresentation on the
basis of the share price alone.
Even though the theory of fraud on the market has a place in the
securities law of this nation, it is a stranger to New Jersey's
securities laws. It is also not consistent with the current
requirements for a common-law action for fraud in New Jersey. Use of
the fraud-on-the-market theory is not the equivalent of proof of
indirect reliance that is required minimally in a common-law fraud
action. Because we discern no compelling reason to deviate from our
current standard of proof for the reliance element in a common-law
fraud action, and because we, like many commentators, cast a jaundiced
eye on the worth of the fraud-on-the-market theory, we decline to
expand our common law to permit its use. Accordingly, we reverse the
judgment of the Appellate Division and reinstate the trial court's
dismissal of plaintiff's fraud claim.
I.
This matter comes before the Court as a result of the Law
Division's grant of summary judgment for the defendants. Accordingly,
we give the plaintiff the benefit of every positive inference to be
drawn from the facts as she has pled them.
See Brill v. Guardian Life
Ins. Co. of Am.,
142 N.J. 520, 523 (1995). In that light, we thus
consider the facts.
i-Stat is a public New Jersey corporation that manufactures and
markets diagnostic blood-analysis equipment designed to assist medical
professionals at the point of patient care. Specifically, the company
makes a hand-held blood analyzer and cartridges to test individual
patients. The corporation's stock is traded on the NASDAQ National
Market System. On October 31, 1995, during the events at issue in this
action, i-Stat had 11,083,421 shares of common stock issued and
outstanding.
On May 9, 1995, i-Stat announced its financial results for the
first fiscal quarter of 1995, ending March 31. The company reported
net sales of $3,359,000, as compared to reported net sales of
$1,651,000 for the same period in the previous year. The company
reported a net loss of $6,531,000 ($0.59 per share) for the first
quarter as compared with a net loss of $6,056,000 ($0.55 per share) for
the same period in the prior year. Kaufman alleges that, to produce
the improved sales figures, i-StatSee footnote 11 misrepresented acceptance of the
company's products to the public by report[ing] sales that were not,
in fact, true sales, but were, instead, loans on a trial basis. For
example, i-Stat allegedly reported sales to certain hospitals without
disclosing that the sales were induced by charitable donations from
interested third parties to the purchasing hospitals. These sales
practices resulted in an exaggerated representation of the company's
sales and degree of market acceptance of its products.
On May 22, 1995, Susan Kaufman purchased one hundred shares of i
Stat common stock at 21 3/4, a total investment of $2175. Meanwhile,
on that date,
Forbes magazine reported that a medical investment
newsletter believed i-Stat was experiencing difficulties and that its
products were not economical. On June 21, 1995, an article in
The
Financial Post, a Canadian financial publication, reported the
expected profitability and growth of the Company, citing an interview
with defendant Imants Lauks. On September 21, 1995, i-Stat reached its
all-time high, trading at 43 3/4.
The bubble began to burst on January 28, 1996. On that date,
The
New York Times reported that Daniel R. Frank, manager of the Fidelity
Advisor Strategic Opportunities Fund, whose successor is still the
largest institutional holder of i-Stat, had made charitable
contributions to hospitals to enable them to obtain i-Stat's diagnostic
equipment.
Then, on March 19, 1996,
The Wall Street Journal reported that the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) was investigating i-Stat's
business. The article revealed that some of i-Stat's sales had been
loans of the products to hospitals on a trial basis rather than actual
sales. i-Stat responded with a press release confirming the SEC's
investigation and inquiry into its sales procedures. On that same day,
i-Stat's shares, which had been declining, tumbled 2½ to 28 3/4. Two
million shares of i-Stat, nearly one sixth of the shares outstanding on
that date, traded on March 19.
On May 20, 1996, Kaufman sold 50 shares at 20 1/4. On June 19,
she filed suit as putative class representative on behalf of all
purchasers of i-Stat common stock between May 9, 1995, and March 19,
1996, excluding the officers and directors of the company. Kaufman
alleged common-law fraud and negligent misrepresentation, contending
that i-Stat's deliberately false and misleading statements regarding
its financial status and deceptive sales practices inflated the stock
price during the class period. Kaufman also alleged that i-Stat's
officers and directors illegally received over $2.9 million from
insider trading during the class period.
i-Stat filed an answer alleging various affirmative defenses.
Both parties stipulated to the following: (1) Kaufman did not
actually or directly receive or rely on any communication containing
any misrepresentation . . . nor . . . actually receive or rely on any
communication which omitted material facts[;] (2) Kaufman purchased
her stock through a brokerage firm and did not directly receive or rely
on any communication from the brokerage firm concerning the i-Stat
purchase; and (3) Kaufman relied exclusively on the integrity of the
market price of i-Stat stock at the time of her purchase. Therefore,
Kaufman's satisfaction of the reliance element of the common-law fraud
and negligent misrepresentation claims depends entirely on the fraud
on-the-market theory.
i-Stat moved for summary judgment on the ground that Kaufman
failed to state a cause of action in fraud or in negligent
misrepresentation because she could not satisfy the actual reliance
requirement in each. The trial court granted the motion, dismissing
Kaufman's claims with prejudice. Although the court agreed with the
fraud-on-the-market theory Justice Blackmun espoused in
Basic,
supra, it rejected the theory as a substitute for reliance,
believing it would be inappropriate for a trial court to expand the
common law of New Jersey. The court concluded that the issue was
better addressed by an appellate court or the Legislature.
On appeal, the Appellate Division reversed the dismissal of
plaintiff's complaint on the common-law-fraud claim but affirmed the
dismissal of the negligent-misrepresentation claim.
Kaufman v. i
Stat Corp.,
324 N.J. Super. 344, 348 (App. Div. 1999). The court
concluded that plaintiff's reliance on the integrity of the market
price of the security was sufficient to satisfy the reliance
requirement of a common-law-fraud claim when the security was
inflated artificially by the corporation's deliberate false
statements, but declined to extend this form of proof of reliance to
a negligent-misrepresentation claim, citing public policy
considerations in favor of a more limited scope of liability for
negligent communication of fraudulent misrepresentations. Because
the Appellate Division broke new ground in allowing the fraud-on
the-market theory to serve as proof of reliance in a common-law
fraud cause of action, we detail the court's reasoning below.
The court began its analysis by noting that only the reliance
element was at issue in this common-law-fraud claim and that New
Jersey already allows proof of indirect reliance to satisfy this
element.
Id. at 349. Indirect reliance has also been adopted by
the
Restatement (Second) of Torts for situations involving reliance
by party B on a false representation initially made to party A who
the maker knew or had reason to expect would communicate the
information to party B such that the information would influence
party B's conduct in a transaction.
Ibid. (citing
Restatement
(Second) of Torts § 533 (1977)).
Using a similar analysis, reasoned the Appellate Division,
federal courts have permitted the reliance element of a securities
fraud claim under section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of
1934 to be satisfied by reliance on the market price of the
security.
Id. at 350-51 (citing
Basic,
supra). Under the fraud-on
the-market theory, the market price reflects the value of the stock
to the investor based on all of the information available at the
time. Therefore, an investor relying on a price that is actually
based on misrepresentations is entitled to recover damages when he
or she trades at a loss.
Id. at 350. The Appellate Division
concluded that the reasoning of the federal securities law cases
should apply to common-law-fraud claims for securities fraud because
the reliance element of a securities fraud claim under these
regulatory provisions is substantially the same as in a common law
fraud action.
Id. at 351.
The Appellate Division acknowledged that no other state
appellate court had permitted the fraud-on-the-market theory to
satisfy the reliance requirement of common-law fraud, but found the
reasoning of the dissenting justices of the California Supreme Court
in
Mirkin v. Wasserman,
858 P.2d 568, 584-95
(Cal. 1993) (Kennard &
Mosk, JJ., concurring in part and dissenting in part), to be
persuasive on the issue. The Appellate Division determined that
that dissent more correctly interpreted principles of indirect
reliance articulated in
Basic and section 533 of the
Restatement
(Second) of Torts, and provided victims of securities fraud with an
appropriate remedy under state law.
Kaufman,
supra, 324
N.J. Super.
at 352. The court rejected i-Stat's argument that plaintiff already
had an adequate remedy under federal securities law because Congress
enacted the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 to supplement, rather
than preempt, existing remedies.
Id. at 353.
In examining the negligent-misrepresentation claim, the
Appellate Division concluded differently. The court acknowledged
that the measure of liability for negligent misrepresentation
'involves a weighing of the relationship of the parties, the nature
of the risk, and the public interest in the proposed solution.'
Ibid. (quoting
Goldberg v. Housing Auth.,
38 N.J. 578, 583 (1962)).
In
H. Rosenblum, Inc. v. Adler,
93 N.J. 324, 352 (1983), this Court
imposed liability on an independent accountant who issued financial
statements on which reasonably foreseeable recipients relied for
business purposes. Given the facts in that matter, the Court did
not reach the issue of claims by individuals who do not receive
audited statements from the company, like purchasers of the
corporation's stock.
Id. at 353. Later, the Court clarified that
limited liability was necessary in a negligent misrepresentation
claim to avoid potentially unlimited liability.
Petrillo v.
Bachenberg,
139 N.J. 472, 484 (1995), quoted in
Kaufman,
supra, 324
N.J. Super. at 355. The Appellate Division therefore believed it
was constrained by the precedent of
Rosenblum, and declined to
broaden the scope of liability for negligent misrepresentation.
Ibid. The court reasoned that this result complied with the public
policy of the
Restatement (Second) of Torts § 552, as well as Rule
10b-5 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, which requires
scienter as an element of fraud.
Id. at 355-56. Similarly, the
Mirkin dissent declined to extend liability under a negligent
misrepresentation cause of action where investors indirectly relied
on the market price rather than on direct misstatements.
Id. at 356
(citing
Mirkin,
supra, 858
P.
2d at 595 (Kennard & Mosk, JJ.,
concurring in part and dissenting in part)).
We granted certification.
162 N.J. 489 (1999).
II.
Assuming the allegations made by plaintiff Susan Kaufman on
behalf of a putative class are correct, and because this is an
appeal of a grant of summary judgment we give her the benefit of
every inference that they are, then the misrepresentations and
omissions made by the management of i-Stat corporation caused her to
lose money. If she can prove that her loss resulted from an act
prohibited under Section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of
1934,
15 U.S.C.A.
§78j(b), and Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder,
17
C.F.R. § 240.10b-5, she is entitled to compensation for that
loss.
Rule 10b-5 makes it
unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly,
by the use of any means or instrumentality of
interstate commerce, or of the mails or of any
facility of any national securities exchange,
(a) To employ any device, scheme, or artifice to
defraud,
(b) To make any untrue statement of a material
fact or to omit to state a material fact
necessary in order to make the statements made,
in the light of the circumstances under which
they were made, not misleading, or
(c) To engage in any act, practice, or course of
business which operates or would operate as a
fraud or deceit upon any person, in connection
with the purchase or sale of any security.
The misdeeds that plaintiff alleges i-Stat to have committed, if
proven, clearly fall within the ambit of the Rule. Many actions
based on similar claims, some using the fraud-on-the-market theory,
have been brought before the federal courts over the last sixty
years. But since 1995, plaintiffs in these actions have
increasingly turned to state courts.
See SEC, Office of the General
Counsel, Report to The President and The Congress on The First Year
of Practice under The Private Securities Litigation Reform Act of
1995 (April 1997).
The change has come about neither because state courts have
greater expertise in these matters nor because they are more
convenient. The impetus for these state court filings was provided
by Congress' passage of the Private Securities Litigation Reform Act
of 1995,
109 Stat. 737 (PSLRA). Congress enacted the PSLRA to
reduce or eliminate class-action strike suits filed by investors
when the price of a stock declined. PSLRA's provisions have made
litigating such cases much more difficult for plaintiffs.
Among the restrictions imposed was a stay of discovery during
the pendency of any motion to dismiss, Congress having found that
plaintiffs often used this period as a fishing expedition to
discover information that would underlie the suit.
15 U.S.C.A.
§78u-4(b)(3). Similarly, the level of specificity required in
pleadings was raised to a strong inference of fraud, so that any
material misstatement has to be identified, and the information
about, or belief in, any material omission stated with
particularity.
Id. (1), (2). The plaintiff must prove that the
misstatement led to the loss.
Id. (4). Forward-looking statements
are protected by a safe-harbor provision.
15 U.S.C.A.
§78u-4(g).
Class certification is more difficult as a result, and there are
penalties for abusive litigation.
Id. (a), (c). The PSLRA also has
reduced plaintiffs' potential recovery, limiting damages to
the difference between the purchase or sale
price paid or received, as appropriate, by the
plaintiff for the subject security and the mean
trading price of that security during the 90-day
period beginning on the date on which the
information correcting the misstatement or
omission that is the basis for the action is
disseminated to the market.
[
15 U.S.C.A.
§78u-4(e)(1).]
These changes have led plaintiffs to attempt to avoid some of
the new provisions of the [PSLRA] by seeking procedural advantages
available in state courts. Sara Beth Brody & Ted F. Angus,
Securities Litigation in State Court, 1070 WESTLAW PLI/Corp 413
(1998). The result has been a significant forum shift in class
action securities fraud litigation, from federal to state court.
Michael A. Perino, Fraud and Federalism: Preempting Private State
Securities Fraud Causes of Action
50 Stan. L. Rev. 273, 273 (1998).
Plaintiffs are filing 'weaker' cases in state court, i.e., cases in
which the plaintiffs' attorney has a lower expectation that the
complaint will survive a motion to dismiss under the act's 'strong
inference of fraud' pleading standard [because] in state court
proceedings . . . the 'strong inference of fraud' standard does not
apply. Id. at 278, 315.
Most of those cases newly brought in state court have been, as
this one is, substitutes for Rule 10b-5 actions.See footnote 22 To maintain those
actions' viability, the plaintiffs bringing them have sought to have
the courts hearing them incorporate the doctrine of fraud on the
market into the common law of their respective states. Plaintiff,
however, has cited no case in which a state court ruling on its
common law has accepted the invitation. Defendants, by contrast,
have found several cases declining to allow the fraud-on-the-market
theory to establish reliance at common law. See Mirkin v.
Wasserman,
858 P.2d 568, 580 (Cal. 1993) (declining to expand
common-law cause of action when procedurally controlled state
statutory remedy, amenable to fraud-on-the-market presumption,
already available); Malone v. Brincat,
722 A.2d 5 (Del. 1998)
(declining to expand common-law cause of action when federal
statutory remedy available); Kahler v. E.F. Hutton Co.,
558 So.2d 144 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1990); Constantine v. Miller Indus., No.
E1999-01575-COA-R3-CV, 2
000 WL 336663 (Tenn. Ct. App. March 31,
2000). See also Rosenthal v. Dean Witter Reynolds, Inc.,
908 P.2d 1095, 1104 (Colo. 1995) (rejecting related doctrine of fraud
created the market and requiring actual reliance on substance of
misrepresentation). Our research reveals that one court has
accepted the theory in dictum, but no claim based directly on the
theory appears to have been adjudicated in the jurisdiction. Allyn
v. Wortman,
725 So.2d 94 (Miss. 1998).
The federal courts with jurisdiction in New Jersey have
rejected the idea that fraud on the market can create a common-law
action for fraud. Thus, the Third Circuit, in one of the landmark
decisions on fraud on the market, Peil v. Speiser,
806 F.2d 1154 (3d
Cir. 1986), on which the Supreme Court relied extensively in Basic,
declined to allow a state-law claim to proceed because no state
courts have adopted the theory, and thus direct reliance remains a
requirement of a common law securities fraud claim. Id. at 1163
(adjudicating Pennsylvania-law claim). The District of New Jersey
has also rejected the invitation to expand the common law of fraud.
See Weikel v. Tower Semiconductor Ltd.,
183 F.R.D. 377, 400 n.12
(D.N.J. 1998); Easton & Co. v. Mutual Benefit Life Ins. Co., 1
993 WL 89146, at *6 (D.N.J.); Cammer v. Bloom,
711 F. Supp. 1264, 1298
(D.N.J. 1989); In re ORFA Sec. Litig.,
654 F. Supp. 1449, 1460
(D.N.J. 1987) ("There does [sic] not appear to be any common law
exceptions to the requirement of individual reliance (analogous to
the judicially created Rule 10b-5 exceptions)"). But see In re
Zenith Labs. Sec. Litig., 1
993 WL 260683 (D.N.J.) (predicting that
New Jersey Supreme Court would allow fraud-on-the-market proof of
negligent misrepresentation and allowing negligent-misrepresentation
claims to survive summary judgment).
The many state-law class actions for securities fraud triggered
further federal reform legislation, the Securities Litigation
Uniform Standards Act of 1998, Pub. L. No. 105-353,
112 Stat. 3227,
(codified in scattered sections of
15 U.S.C.A.
§§77-80) (SLUSA).
In his signing statement on the bill, President Clinton noted
concerns that PSLRA's protections had not taken full effect because
firms [were] not using the Federal safe harbor for forward-looking
statements because they fear[ed] State court litigation over the
same representations that are protected under Federal law [and]
State actions [were] being used to achieve an 'end run' around
[PSLRA's] stay of discovery. 1
998 U.S.C.C.A.N. 768. Now, SLUSA
provides that any securities action brought on behalf of a class of
more than fifty individual investors, whether arising under federal,
common, or blue-sky law, must be brought in federal court.
15 U.S.C.A.
§77b. Since the common law of fraud covers areas other
than securities, then, the plaintiffs in this case are asking this
Court to expand the common law, potentially beyond the arena of
securities, in an action of a sort that Congress substantially has
barred our courts from hearing in the future.
To some degree, SLUSA allows the Court to consider this claim
free from the threat that securities-fraud plaintiffs will bring
actions in New Jersey with only the most tenuous of connections here
because this is the only state that allows them to do so.
Nevertheless, the excepted plaintiffs remaining under SLUSA, namely
state or municipal entities, state pension funds, or combinations of
the same, could still bring a significant amount of litigation here.
Further, SLUSA excepts classes of fewer than fifty plaintiffs.
Federalism permits the state and national governments to
resolve similar matters in different ways. See State v. Preciose,
129 N.J. 451, 475 (1992) (considerations of federalism dictate that
our state courts should enforce New Jersey's post-conviction rules
without attempting to emulate the federal habeas decisions). A
court's decision to follow its own lead, however, ought to be firmly
grounded in public policy. Cf. State v. Hempele,
120 N.J. 182, 229
(1990) (Garibaldi, J., dissenting) (observing that under principles
of federalism, there is no sound public policy that would justify
departure from federal approach in Fourth Amendment case). The
question in this matter is whether the public interest in the
development of our common law of fraud is served by plaintiff's
contention that the fraud-on-the-market theory should be permitted
to be used in New Jersey despite a contrary conclusion in the many
other jurisdictions that have considered the same question.
III.
A.
Plaintiff characterizes the fraud-on-the-market theory as no
more than a reasonable application of indirect reliance principles.
Indirect reliance allows a plaintiff to prove a fraud action when he
or she heard a statement not from the party that defrauded him or
her but from that party's agent or from someone to whom the party
communicated the false statement with the intention that the victim
hear it, rely on it, and act to his or her detriment.
See Judson v.
Peoples Bank & Trust Co.,
25 N.J. 17, 27 (1957);
Metric Inv., Inc.
v. Patterson,
101 N.J. Super. 301, 306-07 (App. Div. 1968). The
Appellate Division accepted plaintiff's argument, noting that the
fraud-on-the-market theory of federal securities fraud law was
[b]ased on a similar analysis, and holding that indirect reliance
in the form of reliance on the integrity of the market price for a
corporate security which has been artificially inflated by the
corporation's deliberate false statements concerning its financial
condition may satisfy the reliance element of a common law fraud
action.
Kaufman,
supra, 324
N.J. Super. at 350, 354.
Defendants note this shift from a chain of communicated false
statements, however indirectly passed along from one to another, and
argue that this Court's standard for reliance, even indirect
reliance, requires that the plaintiff have actually relied on the
misstatement, i.e., that the plaintiff actually received and
considered the misstatement or omission, however indirectly uttered,
before he or she completed the transaction. Defendant argues that
until the decision below, no New Jersey state court [had] stretched
the limits of common law liability to encompass a situation [in
which] plaintiff never actually received or relied on any of the
alleged misstatements.
We agree with defendants. The actual receipt and consideration
of any misstatement remains central to the case of any plaintiff
seeking to prove that he or she was deceived by the misstatement or
omission. The element of reliance is the same for fraud and
negligent misrepresentation.
Compare Rosenblum,
supra, 93
N.J. at
334 (Negligent misrepresentation is . . . [a]n incorrect statement,
negligently made and justifiably relied on, [and] may be the basis
for recovery of damages for economic loss . . . sustained as a
consequence of that reliance.)
with Gennari v. Weichert Co.
Realtors,
148 N.J. 582, 610 (1997) (The five elements of common-law
fraud are: (1) a material misrepresentation of a presently existing
or past fact; (2) knowledge or belief by the defendant of its
falsity; (3) an intention that the other person rely on it; (4)
reasonable reliance thereon by the other person; and (5) resulting
damages.).
See also Kuhnel v. CNA Ins. Cos.,
322 N.J. Super. 568,
581 (App. Div. 1999) (affirming trial court's dismissal of fraud and
negligent-misrepresentation claims for plaintiffs' failure to show
detrimental reliance).
With regard to a negligent-misrepresentation claim, in
Rosenblum,
supra, while finding that an accounting firm could be
liable to someone relying on its statements, even though that party
was not its client, we nevertheless held that plaintiffs alleging
deceit would have to establish that they . . . received . . . the
statements . . . that they relied on the statements and that the
misstatements therein . . . were a proximate cause of the . . .
damage.
Id. at 350 (citations omitted). We laid out plaintiff's
burden this way to retain the concept of reliance defined in
Judson,
Metric, and their antecedents and at the same time avoid potentially
unlimited liability for the makers of the statements to parties
other than those to whom the statements were made.
Petrillo v.
Bachenberg,
139 N.J. 472, 484 (1995).
Because negligent misrepresentation does not require scienter
as an element, it is easier to prove than fraud. The Appellate
Division correctly reasoned that, because the Rule 10b-5 action
requires a plaintiff to prove scienter, expanding fraud on the
market to cover a tort without scienter would be inconsistent with
the theory of recovery.
Kaufman,
supra, 324
N.J. Super. at 355-56.
Nevertheless, our law of indirect reliance, even though most
recently clarified in negligent-misrepresentation cases, is the same
in fraud cases, the element of reliance being the same in both.
B.
Other states similarly have held that the doctrine of indirect
reliance requires that the plaintiff have relied on the substance of
the allegedly fraudulent claim. The Florida District Court of
Appeals, which has rejected the fraud-on-the-market theory,
see
Kahler,
supra, distinguished its acceptance of indirect reliance
because, with indirect reliance, the actual substance of the
misrepresentation is communicated to the plaintiff at the end of a
series of communications begun by the defendant with the intent that
the plaintiff will hear the misrepresentation.
See Joseph v. Norman
LaPorte Realty, Inc.,
508 So.2d 496 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1987).
Similarly, the California Court of Appeal recently held,
relying on
Mirkin,
supra, [i]t must be shown the defendant made
misrepresentations or omissions directly to one victim who then
repeated the misrepresentations or omissions to another who thus was
an indirect recipient of the defendant's communications.
Gawara v.
United States Brass Corp.,
74 Cal. Rptr.2d 663, 672 (reversing
plaintiffs' verdict for failing to establish all the necessary
links in the chain).
In
Mirkin, the plaintiffs, as here, invoked Section 533 of the
Restatement of Torts (Second), which states that:
The maker of a fraudulent misrepresentation is
subject to liability for pecuniary loss to
another who acts in justifiable reliance upon it
if the misrepresentation, although not made
directly to the other, is made to a third person
and the maker intends or has reason to expect
that its terms will be repeated or its substance
communicated to the other, and that it will
influence his conduct in the transaction or type
of transaction involved.
The court, however, rejected the plaintiffs' proposition that a
scheme allowing a person to state a claim based on secondhand
misrepresentations also allowed reliance to be presumed on behalf of
market investors.
Mirkin,
supra,
858 P.2d 576. Instead, the court
noted, [r]eliance at common law has two components--awareness of
the misrepresentation and action based thereon. The plaintiff in a
fraud-on-the-market case under Rule 10b-5
is not required to prove
the first component.
Id. at 579 n.8 (emphasis added).
C.
Indirect reliance remains today what we held it to be in
Judson
and
Rosenblum,
supra. If proven, it is an element of a claim of
fraud. If a party to a transaction makes a false statement to
another party, intending or knowing that the other party in the
transaction will hear it and rely on it, and the second party to the
transaction actually hears the substance of the misrepresentation,
by means however attenuated, and considers the actual content of
that misrepresentation when making the decision to complete the
transaction, then that person has established indirect reliance to
support a fraud claim.
In this case, plaintiff has explicitly stated that she did not
consider i-Stat's financial statements, either by herself or in
consultation with an investment professional, but acted only on the
market price. By that statement she denies that she ever considered
i-Stat's sales volume in her buying decision. Thus, she has failed
to establish that she relied, however indirectly, on the
misstatements of i-Stat and its management. Therefore, under our
traditional standard for proof of reliance, even indirect reliance,
plaintiff fails to show reliance and, therefore, fails to make out a
claim for fraud.
IV.
In her brief, plaintiff correctly avers that, because she
brought her claim before the enactment of SLUSA, she was clearly
entitled . . . to seek redress under state law in state court. New
Jersey provides, as do the other states and jurisdictions, a
comprehensive statutory scheme of securities regulation and investor
protection, the Uniform Securities Law (1997),
N.J.S.A. 49:3-47 to
76 (the USL). Plaintiff here, however, has chosen not to proceed
under the USL because the USL requires privity in securities-fraud
actions and thus will not allow her to reach the issuer of her
shares or its officers.
See N.J.S.A. 49:3-71.
Although requiring privity can seem harsh when, as here, the
victim of the alleged misstatement or omission is remote from the
offending party, our Legislature imposed the requirement of privity
to counterbalance an advantage for plaintiffs. The USL's drafters
rejected any requirement that the buyer prove reliance on the
untrue statement or the omission. He must show only that
he did not
know of it. Louis Loss,
Commentary on the Uniform Securities Act
148 (1976) (Draftsmen's Commentary to § 410(a)). As a result,
securities-fraud plaintiffs need only prove the misrepresentations
and their ignorance of them, a significantly lower burden than that
imposed by a common-law fraud action. As the Supreme Court of
California stated in
Mirkin,
supra, 858
P.
2d at 580 (construing
California securities statute) the very purpose of [a statutory
securities-fraud action] is to afford the victims of securities
fraud . . . a remedy without the formidable task of proving common
law fraud (quotations omitted).
Plaintiff in this action asks to be relieved of that burden in
another fashion, preferable to her, through the use of the theory of
fraud on the market. The Legislature, however, has already clearly
stated its choice in approaching securities-fraud complaints: it did
not lessen the proof required to demonstrate reliance on a
misrepresentation, but instead eliminated reliance as an element of
securities fraud entirely in favor of a system in which privity
establishes causation.
See David O. Blood, Comment,
There Should Be
No Reliance in the Blue Sky, 1
998
BYU L. Rev. 177, 205-08
(commenting on Uniform Securities Act of 1956, model for USL). The
Legislature balanced the plaintiff's advantage of not having to show
reliance with the defendant's advantage of being immune from
liability to anyone out of privity. The USL reflects other balances
as well, such as a shorter limitations period _ two years instead of
six years for common-law fraud _ and a provision that actions and
damages are limited to those provided in the statute.
N.J.S.A.
49:3-71(g),(c).
While the USL does not control the development of the common
law in this area, we are informed by the choices made by the
Legislature when it enacted the state statutory scheme for
securities fraud. Accordingly, plaintiff's arguments concerning the
policy benefits of adopting fraud on the market as a method of
proving reliance in common-law fraud may be evaluated from the
vantage point of understanding the policy choices made by our
Legislature in the USL, which are unhelpful to plaintiffs here; the
deliberations of other jurisdictions that have considered the
theory; and analysis of the theory by academics.
V.
Since the Supreme Court accepted fraud on the market in
Basic,
supra, twelve years ago, no state court with the authority to
consider whether
Basic is persuasive has chosen to apply it to
claims arising under its own state's laws. In considering whether
to accept the theory, then, the persuasiveness of its intellectual
underpinning, the Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis, or ECMH,
requires close examination. The ECMH proposes that the price of a
stock reflects information known about a corporation whose
securities trade publicly. The extent to which the price reflects
that information is expressed by the three different forms of market
efficiency--strong, semi-strong, and weak.
In a strong-form efficient market, all information that exists
about a company and would be of interest to a purchaser of the
company's securities is reflected, nearly instantaneously, in the
price of the stock, such that no individual can expect to gain a
greater return from that security than from any other security, and
no individual can hope to perform better than any other individual
over the long term. The weak form of the ECMH, by contrast,
proposes that the price of the stock eventually reflects publicly
available information. There is widespread agreement among
economists and investment professionals that the national stock
markets of the United States display weak-form efficiency.
See
Barbara Black,
Fraud on the Market: A Criticism of Dispensing with
Reliance Requirements in Certain Open Market Transactions,
62
N.C.
L. Rev. 435, 438 n.8 (1984).
Semi-strong efficiency, which is somewhere between the other
two forms in holding that most information about a company is
reflected in its price fairly quickly, appears to be the form
assumed to exist by the United States Supreme Court in
Basic.
See
Nathaniel Carden, Comment,
Implications of the Private Securities
Litigation Reform Act of 1995 for Judicial Presumptions of Market
Efficiency,
65
U. Chi. L. Rev. 879, 883 (1998).
The ECMH, perhaps because it posits that no investor can
consistently outperform the market regardless of the amount of
research or work undertaken beforehand, is a favorite subject for
academics but is often discounted by investment professionals. For
example, Warren Buffett, the well-known, successful investor,
contends that proper study of a company's financial condition
reveals its value far better than does the market price of its
shares. Roger Lowenstein,
Buffett: The Making of an American
Capitalist 307-22 (1995).
The ECMH has suffered at the hands of academic writers as well:
We think that the legal rush to embrace and
apply the efficient market hypothesis has been
overly precipitous and occasionally unwise . . .
. [M]ore recent economic research and
controversy about the hypothesis casts doubt on
E[C]MH's empirical claims and theoretical
underpinnings. Whether markets are efficient in
the sense claimed by the initial tests is now
highly suspect . . . . Virtually none of this
doubt, however, has been reflected in the
debates about the implications of the efficient
market hypothesis for legal decisionmaking.
[Jeffrey N. Gordon & Lewis A. Kornhauser,
Efficient Markets, Costly Information, and
Securities Research,
60
N.Y.U. L. Rev. 761, 764
(1985).]
As more time has passed, and there has been greater opportunity to
examine and test market efficiency, the hypothesis has shown greater
weakness.
The debate over the ECMH is fundamental because
[it] is a major premise for a substantial body
of corporate and securities law and scholarship
[and] the United States Supreme Court has
recognized the ECMH as a basis for satisfying
the reliance requirement in certain
securities-fraud cases. Moreover, since the
late 1970s, a great deal of corporate and
securities law scholarship has extolled the
virtues of the ECMH and urged it as a basis to
advocate many major policy prescriptions.
Indeed, before the public capital market crash
of October 1987, only a few sobering pieces
stood to remind the legal community that the
ECMH is only a hypothesis, and a dubious one at
that.
[Lawrence A. Cunningham,
From Random Walks to
Chaotic Crashes: The Linear Genealogy of the
Efficient Capital Market Hypothesis,
62
Geo.
Wash. L. Rev. 546, 548-49 (1994).]
Because the ECMH fails to adjust for the noise and chaos
inevitable in any system created by the acts of so many
participants, one observer has gone so far as to contend that
obsolescence renders the ECMH false in all its forms.
Id. at 548.
Other writers have commented on causation uncertainty in
understanding market reactions, noting, among other things: how
inefficiently prices reflect earnings; how other publicly available
financial information is underreflected; how other information, such
as historical underperformance, affects price; and how the
activities of underrational noise traders and those otherwise
affected by investor sentiment distort the picture.
See Victor L.
Bernard, et al.,
Challenges to the Efficient Market Hypothesis:
Limits to the Applicability of Fraud-on-the-Market Theory,
73
Neb.
L. Rev. 781, 786-92 (1994).
Plaintiff argues that the academic debate goes to whether
particular securities trade in efficient markets and that academics
and courts remain confident that the markets are efficient.
Defendants acknowledge that uncertainty whether the markets are
efficient may not be reason enough to reject fraud on the market
where it has already been accepted, but argues that a theory, whose
validity at best remains in question, provides poor support for an
expansion of the common law.
Our own Chancery Division has noted the uncertainty regarding
the validity of the ECMH:
Most academics in the field of finance advocate
a combination of the random walk and the
efficient market theories. Most Wall Street
professionals, the security analysts and
portfolio managers, disagree. The academics say
that the stock market is self-regulating as it
reacts to new information, and random selection
of investments will follow the market. The most
dramatic example was the Forbes index, composed
of twenty stocks chosen by throwing darts at a
list of securities on the stock exchange.
Professor Thaler and others believe that profits
can be made from cracks in the efficient market,
and the relative strength theory is another
gloss on the random walk-efficient market
theories. It has been supported, as well as
criticized, in the literature.
[Johnson v. Johnson,
212 N.J. Super. 368, 392 (1986).]
Other courts have also expressed misgivings about the ECMH. In
Mirkin,
supra, the California Supreme Court accepted that fraud on
the market could underlie a statutory action, but expressly declined
to accept or reject the ECMH even though that court did acknowledge
that the dissemination of material information affects the prices of
securities. 858
P.
2d at 579 & n.7. Also, Chancellor Allen noted,
just as the Constitution does not enshrine Mr. Herbert Spencer's
social statics, neither does the common law of directors' duties
elevate the theory of a single, efficient capital market to the
dignity of a sacred text.
Paramount Comms. Inc. v. Time Inc. 1
989 WL 79880, *19 (Del. Ch. July 14, 1989),
aff'd
571 A.2d 1140 (Del.
1989).
Even at the time of the
Basic decision, skeptical voices were
heard. Dissenting from the majority opinion, Justice White wrote
that with no staff economists, no experts schooled in the
'efficient-capital-market hypothesis,' no ability to test the
validity of empirical market studies, we are not well equipped to
embrace novel constructions of a statute based on contemporary
microeconomic theory.
485 U.S. 224 at 253, 108
S. Ct. at 994-995,
99
L. Ed.
2d at 222. There is no greater proof now than there was
then that the theoretical foundation for the fraud-on-the-market
theory is as strong as its proponents maintain.
Yet now, despite there being no basis for increased acceptance
of the idea of fraud on efficient markets, plaintiff asks us to
expand its use beyond the carefully balanced world of the federal
securities laws to the vastly more diverse universe of common-law
fraud claims. In addition to our skepticism concerning its validity
when used in the context of securities markets, we note that
plaintiffs in other jurisdictions have attempted to establish that
markets in assets other than securities are efficient enough to
allow use of the fraud-on-the-market theory. Various opinions we
have examined have rejected use of the theory in those other
settings. The Alabama Supreme Court has rejected the fraud-on-the
market theory numerous times in the consumer fraud context.
See Ex
parte Household Retail Servs., Inc.,
744 So.2d 871 (1999);
Ex parte
Exxon Corp.,
725 So.2d 930 (1998);
Butler v. Audio/Video
Affiliates, Inc.,
611 So.2d 330 (1992).
See also Sing v. John L.
Scott, Inc.,
948 P.2d 816 (Wash. 1997) (Talmadge, J., dissenting)
(asserting consumer fraud on the market created by interested real
estate agent insider dealing in competitive transaction between
agent and principal).
The Appellate Division of the Supreme Court of New York was
presented with the theory in an action for malpractice against
accountants who allegedly gave improper tax advice to partners in
tax shelters.
Ackerman v. Price Waterhouse,
683 N.Y.S.2d 179
(1998). That court also dealt with the attempt of a season
ticketholder of the then-New York Nets to rely on a fraud-on-the
market approach in certifying his fellow ticketholders as a class
that had been defrauded when the team sold Julius Erving to the
Philadelphia 76ers in 1976.
See Strauss v. Long Island Sports,
Inc.,
401 N.Y.S.2d 233 (App. Div. 1978). The plaintiff, who brought
one of seven such actions, asserted that ticketholders were the
equivalent of shareholders in such an action.
Id. at 237.
We express no view on those cases and leave to another day
whether in a proper case we would accept use of a theory akin to
fraud on the market if it were possible to determine reliably
through such a theory that an unheard misrepresentation, in fact,
was the factor inducing a fraudulent transaction. However, the
cases noted above illustrate the danger of importing a specialized
doctrine into an area of law that has general effect, like our
common law of fraud. The doctrine of indirect reliance has
developed with careful consideration given to its impact. Indirect
reliance occurs when a single communication, an inducement to engage
in a fraudulent transaction, is clearly communicated to the
defrauded party. The price of a publicly traded stock, however,
synthesizes a great variety of information and conveys as much of
that information as possible. But the information is jumbled. No
one piece of information survives clearly enough that the share
price can be said to have passed it on clearly. Until study or
experience can prove that an impersonal mechanism can communicate a
single idea clearly, indirect reliance should not be expanded to
include this theoretical model of market performance and excuse this
plaintiff from her obligation to show individual reliance on the
alleged misrepresentation.
Accepting fraud on the market as proof of reliance in a New
Jersey common-law fraud action would undercut the public interest in
preventing forum-shopping, weaken our law of indirect reliance, and
run contrary to the policy direction of the Legislature and
Congress. We decline to expand our law regarding satisfaction of
the reliance element of a fraud action on the basis of a complex
economic theory that has not been satisfactorily proven. In so
holding, we note that plaintiff had available to her an adequate
federal remedy perfectly suited to her complaint. She chose not to
pursue it.
VI.
Accordingly, the decision of the Appellate Division allowing
the reliance element of a fraud claim to be proven by the fraud-on
the-market theory is reversed, and the judgment of the Superior
Court, Law Division is reinstated, dismissing plaintiff's action.
CHIEF JUSTICE PORITZ and JUSTICES COLEMAN and VERNIERO join in
JUSTICE LaVECCHIA's opinion. JUSTICE STEIN filed a separate
dissenting opinion in which JUSTICES O'HERN and LONG join.
SUPREME COURT OF NEW JERSEY
A-
49 September Term 1999
SUSAN KAUFMAN, on behalf of
herself and all others
similarly situated,
Plaintiff-Respondent,
v.
i-STAT CORPORATION; WILLIAM
P. MOFFITT; LIONEL N.
STERLING; IMANTS R. LAUKS and
MATTHIAS PLUM, JR.,
Defendants-Appellants.
STEIN, J., dissenting.
In this appeal, the issue before the Court is whether reliance
on the integrity of the market price for a corporate security
satisfies the reliance element of a cause of action for common law
fraud. The Appellate Division held that it does. Kaufman v. i-Stat
Corp.,
324 N.J. Super. 344 (1999). Because I believe that the
Appellate Division's thorough and well-reasoned opinion reflects the
correct disposition of that issue, I dissent.
I
The narrow issue before the Court is whether the fraud-on-the
market theory of reliance, articulated and adopted by the United
States Supreme Court in
Basic Inc. v. Levinson,
485 U.S. 224, 241
48,
108 S. Ct. 978, 989-92,
99 L. Ed.2d 194, 214-19 (1988),
adequately may satisfy the reliance element of a state law claim for
common law fraud.
A
A common-law fraud action has five elements. They are (1) a
material misrepresentation of a presently existing or past fact; (2)
knowledge or belief by the defendant of its falsity; (3) an
intention that the other person rely on it; (4) reasonable reliance
thereon by the other person; and (5) resulting damages.
Gennari v.
Weichert Co. Realtors,
148 N.J. 582, 610 (1997).
Since 1957 New Jersey has recognized that indirect reliance may
satisfy the reliance element of a common law fraud action. See
Judson v. Peoples Bank & Trust Co.,
25 N.J. 17, 27 (1957) (holding
that misrepresentation by one family member made with intent that it
be communicated to other family members sufficient to satisfy
reliance element of common law fraud and observing that reliance
may be found by fair inference);
Metric Investment, Inc. v.
Patterson,
101 N.J. Super. 301, 306 (App. Div. 1968)